House Ad
House Ad
 

Economia Gli economisti (English version)

Who Should Safeguard Financial Stability?

Storia dell'articolo

Chiudi

Questo articolo è stato pubblicato il 30 luglio 2010 alle ore 09:14.


NEW HAVEN – Central bankers around the world failed to see the current financial crisis coming before its beginnings in 2007. Martin Èihák of the International Monetary Fund reported in July 2007 that, of 47 central banks found to publish financial stability reports (FSRs), virtually all gave a positive overall assessment of their domestic financial system in their most recent reports.

And yet, although these central banks failed us before the crisis, they should still play the lead role in preventing the next crisis. That is the conclusion, perhaps counterintuitive, that the Squam Lake Group [http://squamlakegroup.org/], a think tank of 15 academic financial economists to which I belong, reached in our recently published report, .

Macro-prudential regulators (government officials who focus not on the soundness of individual financial institutions, but rather on the stability of the whole financial system) are sorely needed, and central bankers are the logical people to fill this role. Other regulators did no better in predicting this crisis, and are even less suited to prevent the next.

David Cameron’s new government in the United Kingdom apparently came to the same conclusion when it announced plans to transfer regulatory authority from the Financial Services Authority (FSA) to the Bank of England.

But agreement about the regulatory role of central banks is not widely spread. In the United States, for example, there is recognition of the importance of macro-prudential regulation, but not of giving this authority to the Federal Reserve. The newly passed US financial-reform legislation entrusts macro-prudential policy to a new Financial Stability Oversight Council. That is good, but the US Treasury secretary will be the council’s chairman, and the Fed, despite gaining some new powers, will for the most part be only one of many members.

The head of the council is thus a political appointee who serves at the pleasure of the president. Recent history shows that political appointees often fail to take courageous or unpopular steps to stabilize the economy. A modern US president certainly remembers how difficult it was to convince voters to put him where he is, and is perpetually campaigning to maintain approval ratings and to preserve his party’s prospects in the next election. The Treasury secretary is part of the president’s team, and works next door to the White House.

L’articolo continua sotto

Tags Correlati: Alan Abelson | Animal Spirits | Ben Bernanke | Economics at Yale University | Fed | Fed Chairman | FSA | George Akerlof | George W. Bush | Ken Henry Treasury | Politica | Robert Shiller | Squam Lake Group | Stati Uniti d'America | Who

 

George W. Bush won the 2000 election, despite losing the popular vote. In 2003, Bush chose as his Treasury secretary John W. Snow, a railroad president who, as Barron’s columnist Alan Abelson put it, may not be the sharpest knife in the cabinet. Snow obliged the president and gave unquestioning support to his policies until leaving office in 2006, just before the crisis erupted. Under the new law, Snow would have been in charge of the stability of the entire US economy.

One theme that Bush found resonated with voters in his 2004 re-election campaign was that of the ownership society. A successful economy, Bush argued, requires that people learn to take responsibility for their actions, and policies aimed at boosting home ownership would inculcate this virtue on a broader scale. That sounded right to voters, especially if it meant government policies that encouraged the emerging real-estate bubble and made their investments in homes soar in value.

Snow echoed his boss. The American economy is coiled like a spring and ready to go, he chirped in 2003. Two years later, near the very height of the bubbles in the equity and housing markets, he declared that, We can be pleased that the economy is on a good and sustainable path.

But, to Bush’s credit, he also brought in Ben Bernanke in 2006 as Fed Chairman. Not part of Bush’s team, Bernanke was protected from political pressures by America’s long tradition of respect for the Fed’s independence. The choice of Bernanke, an accomplished scholar, apparently reflected Bush’s acceptance of the public’s expectation of a first-rate appointee.

The same problems occur in many other countries. People who are chosen in part to win the next election often find their economic judgment constrained. A news story in 2003 reported, for example, that Australian Secretary to the Treasury Ken Henry had warned of a housing bubble there, but then quickly tried to withdraw his comment, saying that it was not for quotation outside of this room. He did earlier this year finally propose new tax policy to slow the still-continuing Australian housing bubble, but now he can’t get his government to implement it.

By contrast, in recent decades central bankers in many countries have gradually won acceptance for the principle of independence from day-to-day political pressures. The public in much of the world now understands that central bankers will be allowed to do their work without interference from politicians. There is a tradition of the central banker as a worldly philosopher, who stands up for long-term sensible policy, and this tradition makes it politically easier for central bankers to do the right thing.

In fact, while the world’s central banks did not see the current crisis coming and did not take steps before 2007 to relieve the pressures that led to it, they did react decisively and energetically as the crisis unfolded, with coordinated international action. This was facilitated by the tradition of political independence and cooperation that has developed over the years among central bankers.

The crisis has underscored the utmost importance of macro-prudential regulation. Although our central bankers are not perfect judges of financial stability, they are still the people who are in the best political and institutional position to ensure it.

Robert Shiller, Professor of Economics at Yale University and Chief Economist at MacroMarkets LLC, is co-author, with George Akerlof, of Animal Spirits: How Human Psychology Drives the Economy and Why It Matters for Global Capitalism.

Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2010.www.project-syndicate.orgFor a podcast of this commentary in English, please use this link:

Shopping24

Da non perdere

Per l'Italia la carta del mondo

Mentre la crisi reale morde più crudelmente, mentre i mercati finanziari saggiano possibili

In Europa la carta «interna»

Batti e ribatti sui nudi sacrifici degli altri, sull'algido rigore senza paracadute e prima o poi

La commedia di Bruxelles

Al Parlamento europeo è andato in scena il terzo atto di una commedia dal titolo: Regole per le

Guarguaglini: ecco le mie verità

«Ho sempre detto che ero innocente, le conclusioni delle indagini lo dimostrano: nell'archiviazione

Una redistribuzione di buon senso

Arrivano dal ministero della Giustizia le nuove piante organiche dei tribunali. Un intervento

Casa, la banca non ti dà il mutuo? Allora meglio un affitto con riscatto. Come funziona

Il mercato dei mutui in Italia resta al palo. Nell'ultimo mese la domanda di prestiti ipotecari è


Jeff Bezos primo nella classifica di Fortune «businessperson of the year»

Dai libri alla nuvola informatica: Jeff Bezos, fondatore e amministratore delegato di Amazon,

Iron Dome, come funziona il sistema antimissile israeliano che sta salvando Tel Aviv

Gli sporadici lanci di razzi iraniani Fajr-5 contro Gerusalemme e Tel Aviv costituiscono una

Dagli Assiri all'asteroide gigante del 21/12/2012, storia di tutte le bufale sulla fine del mondo

Fine Del Mondo, Armageddon, end of the World, Apocalypse? Sembrerebbe a prima vista roba da