House Ad
House Ad
 

Economia Gli economisti (English version)

The Manufacturing Fallacy

Storia dell'articolo

Chiudi

Questo articolo è stato pubblicato il 27 agosto 2010 alle ore 15:51.


NEW YORK – Economists long ago put to rest the error that Adam Smith made when he argued that manufacturing should be given primacy in a country’s economy. Indeed, in Book II of The Wealth of Nations, Smith condemned as unproductive the labors of churchmen, lawyers, physicians, men of letters of all kinds; players, buffoons, musicians, opera-singers, opera-dancers, etc. We may agree with Smith (and Shakespeare) about the uselessness of lawyers perhaps, but surely not about Olivier, Falstaff, and Pavarotti. But the manufacturing fetish recurs repeatedly, the latest manifestation being in the United States in the wake of the recent crisis.

In mid-1960’s Great Britain, Nicholas Kaldor, the world-class Cambridge economist and an influential adviser to the Labour Party, raised an alarm over deindustrialization. His argument was that an ongoing shift of value added from manufacturing to services was harmful, because manufactures were technologically progressive, whereas services were not. He even got a Labour Chancellor of the Exchequer, James Callaghan, to introduce in 1966 a Selective Employment Tax, which taxed employment in services more heavily than employment in manufactures – a measure that was reversed in 1973, once it was realized that it would hit the tourist industry, which generated badly needed foreign exchange.

Kaldor’s argument was based on the erroneous premise that services were technologically stagnant. This view no doubt reflected a casual empiricism based on the mom-and-pop shops and small post offices that English dons saw when going outside their Oxbridge colleges. But it was clearly at odds with the massive technical changes sweeping across the retail sector, and eventually the communications industry, which soon produced Fedex, faxes, mobile phones, and the Internet.

In fact, the dubious notion that we should select economic activities based on their presumed technical innovativeness has been carried even further, in support of the argument that we should favor semiconductor chips over potato chips. While rejection of this presumption landed Michael Boskin, Chairman of President George H.W. Bush’s Council of Economic Advisers, in rough political waters, the presumption prompted a reporter to go and check the matter for himself. It turned out that semiconductors were being fitted onto circuit boards in a mindless, primitive fashion, whereas potato chips were being produced through a highly automated process (which is how Pringles chips rest on each other perfectly).

L’articolo continua sotto

Tags Correlati: Adam Smith | Diesel | Gran Bretagna | International Economics at the Council | James Callaghan | John Zysman | Law at Columbia University | Michael Boskin | Nicholas Kaldor | Stati Uniti d'America | Stephen Cohen

 

The semi-conductor chips versus potato chips debate also underlined a different point. Many proponents of semiconductor chips also presumed that what you worked at determined whether, in your outlook, you would be a dunce (producing potato chips) or a with-it modernist (producing semiconductor chips).

I have called this presumption a quasi-Marxist fallacy. Marx emphasized the critical role of the means of production. I have argued, on the other hand, that you could produce semiconductor chips, trade them for potato chips, and then munch them while watching TV and becoming a moron. On the other hand, you could produce potato chips, trade them for semiconductor chips that you put into your PC, and become a computer wizard! In short, it is what you consume, not what you produce, that influences what sort of person you will be and how that affects your economy and your society.

Ignorant of the extensive deindustrialization debate in 1960’s Great Britain, two Berkeley academics, Stephen Cohen and John Zysman, started a similar debate in the US in 1987 with their book Manufacturing Matters, which claimed that, without manufactures, a viable service sector is untenable. But this argument is specious: one can have a vigorous transportation industry, with trucks, rail, and air cargo moving agricultural produce within and across nations, as countries such as pre-Peronist Argentina, Australia, New Zealand, and modern Chile have done very successfully.

Cohen and Zysman argued that manufactures were related to services like the crop duster to the cotton fields, the ketchup maker to the tomato patch, and that if you [o]ffshore the tomato farm…you close or offshore the ketchup plant….No two ways about it. My reaction was: [A]s I read the profound assertion about the tomato farm and the ketchup plant, I was eating my favorite Crabtree & Evelyn vintage marmalade. It surely had not occurred to me that England grew its own oranges.

While these episodes reflected academic obsession with manufactures and therefore died early deaths, the same cannot be said for the latest revival of the manufactures fetish in the US and Great Britain. The latest flirtation with supporting manufactures has come from the current crisis, especially in the financial sector, and is therefore likely to have greater prospects for survival. The fetish is particularly rampant in the US, where the Democrats in Congress have gone so far as to ally themselves with lobbyists for manufactures to pass legislation that would provide protection and subsidies to increase the share of manufactures in GDP.

Because of the financial crisis, many politicians have accepted the argument, in a virtual throwback to Adam Smith, that financial services are unproductive – even counterproductive – and need to be scaled back by governmental intervention. It is then inferred that this means that manufactures must be expanded. But this does not follow. Even if you wanted to curtail financial services, you could still focus on the multitude of non-financial services.

Diesel engines and turbines are not the only alternatives; many services, like professional therapy, nursing, and teaching are available. The case for a shift to manufacturing remains unproven, because it cannot be proved.

Jagdish Bhagwati is Professor of Economics and Law at Columbia University and Senior Fellow in International Economics at the Council on Foreign Relations.

Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2010.www.project-syndicate.orgFor a podcast of this commentary in English, please use this link:

Shopping24

Da non perdere

Per l'Italia la carta del mondo

Mentre la crisi reale morde più crudelmente, mentre i mercati finanziari saggiano possibili

In Europa la carta «interna»

Batti e ribatti sui nudi sacrifici degli altri, sull'algido rigore senza paracadute e prima o poi

La commedia di Bruxelles

Al Parlamento europeo è andato in scena il terzo atto di una commedia dal titolo: Regole per le

Guarguaglini: ecco le mie verità

«Ho sempre detto che ero innocente, le conclusioni delle indagini lo dimostrano: nell'archiviazione

Una redistribuzione di buon senso

Arrivano dal ministero della Giustizia le nuove piante organiche dei tribunali. Un intervento

Casa, la banca non ti dà il mutuo? Allora meglio un affitto con riscatto. Come funziona

Il mercato dei mutui in Italia resta al palo. Nell'ultimo mese la domanda di prestiti ipotecari è


Jeff Bezos primo nella classifica di Fortune «businessperson of the year»

Dai libri alla nuvola informatica: Jeff Bezos, fondatore e amministratore delegato di Amazon,

Iron Dome, come funziona il sistema antimissile israeliano che sta salvando Tel Aviv

Gli sporadici lanci di razzi iraniani Fajr-5 contro Gerusalemme e Tel Aviv costituiscono una

Dagli Assiri all'asteroide gigante del 21/12/2012, storia di tutte le bufale sulla fine del mondo

Fine Del Mondo, Armageddon, end of the World, Apocalypse? Sembrerebbe a prima vista roba da